-
Notifications
You must be signed in to change notification settings - Fork 0
New issue
Have a question about this project? Sign up for a free GitHub account to open an issue and contact its maintainers and the community.
By clicking “Sign up for GitHub”, you agree to our terms of service and privacy statement. We’ll occasionally send you account related emails.
Already on GitHub? Sign in to your account
Week 2: Memos - Models of Innovation and Growth #6
Comments
The Role of Mergers and Acquisitions (M&A) in Amplifying Non-Productive Strategies and Stifling InnovationMergers and acquisitions (M&A), particularly those of considerable size (e.g., $500M+), are often framed by C-suites and bankers as strategies to improve efficiency and consolidate resources. However, empirical evidence suggests that such large-scale M&A activities frequently signal a shift in focus from innovation-driven strategies to non-productive tactics aimed at preserving or enhancing market dominance. This behavior is consistent with the dynamics highlighted in Barriers to Creative Destruction, wherein dominant firms prioritize maintaining their position over fostering competition or innovation. A good example is the pharmaceutical industry is dominated by a few major players, including Pfizer, Johnson & Johnson, Merck, Novartis, and Roche. Over the past few decades, these firms have engaged in frequent large-scale M&A, often exceeding the $500M threshold. For instance:
Mechanism of Non-Productive Strategy Amplification
Proposed Formula: M&A and Non-Productive Strategy ImplementationTo measure the impact of M&A on a company's likelihood to implement non-productive strategies, a mathematical representation of this dynamic can be expressed as: Where:
Hypotheses
Policy Implications
|
Patent and Innovation in the Era of AIThe Schumpeterian Growth Theory suggests that the value of innovation is equal to the profit flow divided by the risk-adjusted interest rate, where the risk lies in being displaced by a new innovator. According to this framework, patents can promote innovation by ensuring a relatively high profit flow for a specified period (by granting monopoly power over the commercialization of patented technologies) and reducing the risk of displacement by new entrants. ![]() However, alternative perspectives argue that patents may have minimal impact on innovation and could sometimes even hinder it. Historical evidence suggests that patents did not play a significant role in the invention boom during the Industrial Revolution in the United Kingdom. Many innovations occurred outside the purview of patent laws, relying instead on secrecy for protection. Furthermore, patent-induced litigation often protects incumbents, disproportionately affects late entrants, and may discourage innovation. In the era of AI, the role of patents in fostering innovation is uncertain. On one hand, the widespread availability of information and the open-source nature of many AI products leave less room for secrecy as a protection mechanism for emerging technologies. Research indicates that in sectors and countries where secrecy is less prevalent, innovation tends to rely more heavily on patents. This suggests that patents could play a more critical role in promoting innovation in this era. On the other hand, AI has dramatically increased research productivity and the speed of technological discovery. As a result, companies—both large and small—may arrive at similar or identical innovations within a short timeframe, complicating the fair distribution of patent rights. Moreover, controversies surrounding AI-related patent rules add to this complexity. For instance, the Biden administration’s Inventorship Guidance for AI-Assisted Inventions states that AI-associated technologies can be patented, but it must be proven that at least a human significantly contributed to the development process. This creates uncertainty about the scope of patent protection for certain technologies, potentially impacting how patents influence innovation. According to research article, two remedies have historically addressed issues within the patent system. The first is patent pools, which allow competing firms to combine their patents. The second is compulsory licensing, which enables competitors to produce patented inventions without the consent of the patent owners. Interestingly, data shows that patent pools slowed innovation during the textile era, while compulsory licensing has been shown to encourage innovation, particularly among new entrants, possibly by fostering greater market competition (see below for a graph). ![]() The evolution of patent laws globally remains uncertain, particularly in light of the challenges posed by AI. Policymakers should carefully weigh the positive impacts of patents on innovation against the potential challenges, especially those arising from the unique dynamics of AI. |
One of the Schumpeterian Growth Theory paper's topics is the effect of long-term tech waves on market and firm dynamics. It identifies three key results: 1) technological waves spur an increase in firm entry and exit as new firms innovate and obsolete firms exit the market, 2) they initially generate a productivity slowdown as resources are reallocated, and 3) they cause an initial increase in wage inequality, as workers who adapt quickly to new technologies receive higher wage premiums. These dynamics highlight the disruptive yet transformative nature of technological progress on the economy. I am particularly interested in the effect of new technology on productivity. At its inception, new technology often leads to a productivity slowdown due to resources and labor being diverted from normal productive activities into the learning and development required to integrate the technology. However, over the long term, this investment is expected to yield significant productivity gains. These gains arise from three primary sources: i) an increase in the quality of labor as workers acquire better education and skills tailored to the new technology, ii) an increase in capital stock driven by firms' investments in advanced machinery, computers, and infrastructure, and iii) an improvement in total factor productivity (TFP), which reflects enhanced efficiencies, innovation, and potential reductions in regulatory burdens. Traditionally, Productivity (𝐴) is measured using the Cobb-Douglas Production Function, which relates output (𝑌) to capital (𝐾) and labor (𝐿) inputs: While this model captures the relationship between inputs and output effectively, it does not explicitly account for the nuanced effects of technological change. I propose an alternative measurement of productivity that incorporates the positive and negative shocks from new technology adoption: Where: A = Productivity Hypothesis: delta_1 < 0: Re-education of workers diverts from normal activity This model captures both the short-term disruptions and the long-term benefits of technological waves. It emphasizes that while the initial stages of technology adoption can lead to inefficiencies and economic friction, the resulting improvements in labor quality, capital stock, and total factor productivity drive sustainable growth. |
![]() In this week’s course material, I was piqued by the above graphs from Chapter 4 of the “World Development Report: the Middle-Income Trap.” In the first graph, we notice that there is a downward trend in percentages of firm entry rates in the United States while the second graph informs us that growth is driven by entrants in the United States. Even in the United States’ startup economy, the decline in firm entry rates over time demonstrates that the country is suffering from a decline in dynamism. In my memo I want to ask the question: why? What are the drivers of the United States’ decline in dynamism and how can the trend be reversed? What is the role of AI and industrial policies in reversing this trend? What data sets should we be looking at in order to better understand the nuances of this problem? One idea is that the decline in firm entry rate is related to a massive shift of innovative activity from large corporations, (as demonstrated in the figure B4.1.1 below), which in turn threatens small entrants. Another issue is the political connectivity of large firms. “Connecting to power” outlines that in industries with politically connected incumbents, there are fewer entrants by new firms. This is because small entrants face both productivity and bureaucratic challenges in the competition against established incumbents. In regards to AI, we know that its rise will cause massive displacements across the United States labor force. But AI also has the potential to reverse the US’ decline in dynamism by creating more space for entrants in the economy, fostering greater innovation between entrants and incumbents through creative destruction, and maximizing efficiency in productivity. However, some initial research has shown that if not harnessed with the right policies, there will be risks. For example, major tech giants already have control over the AI market in the United States: such as IBM and Google. Furthermore, the CEOs of OpenAI, Meta, Apple, and more have donated to the Trump inauguration, giving these incumbents more political power and increasing the relative regulatory barriers of entry for smaller firms. The United States Census Bureau demonstrates that AI usage is also more concentrated in larger firms, enhancing their productivity and efficiency and innovation of new products and services. These examples demonstrate how AI can be harmful towards the relationship between entrants and incumbents and stifle innovation. However, although the 2017 and 2018 censuses demonstrated that AI use in producing goods and services increased with firm size, this pattern might be changing with recent advances in generative AI. Researchers argue that generative AI might actually be able to help close the productivity gap between small and large firms, as it has a much greater marginal product of labor for smaller firms than large firms. ![]() ![]() Sources in addition to class readings and lectures: https://www.fastcompany.com/91257772/trump-inauguration-big-tech-donations-list-google-microsoft-meta-apple https://www.census.gov/newsroom/blogs/research-matters/2024/12/ai-use-small-businesses.html |
Hidden costs of SOEs A common argument used in favour of state owned enterprises is that it keeps prices low for everyone involved. This may certainly be the case in the short run where state owned enterprises may offer lower prices for their lack of need to generate a profit. The US Postal Service comes to mind as an example of a monopoly that offers relatively low rates while operating at a loss for extended periods of time. We can likely posit that in the long run it is likely that the lack of competition as well as the lack of incentives to improve efficiency can lead to stagnation. Furthermore, any benefits they bring in low prices can be said to be paid for by taxpayers through a variety of hidden costs. If a competitive, profit-seeking firm cannot match those prices, it is likely because it is unsustainable without some sort of support from the government which has its roots in tax dollars. I want to create a simple model that illustrates the effect of these hidden costs and how they lead to the persistence of state owned enterprises. Really, this argument can be generalized to any special interest group that by virtue of legislation/grants are able to keep competitors at bay be it airlines, mail, trucking, medical care, or subways. Let’s first consider the set of consumers: The firm imposes a cost For the sake of simplicity I incorporate the notion of “hidden costs” by applying Summing over the entire community we get: Which is equal to: Assuming that both parties are indifferent with regards to losses and gains, this shows that the obscurity of costs can have an impact on the perceived value of an issue. While exactly how this might be reflected in the political activities of the two parties is unclear, what is clear is that the upper bound imposed on the resources these two parties will deploy to either secure or prevent some sort of government sponsored advantage is influenced by the cost of getting informed. The model likely needs considerable refinement and additions to incorporate some of the more nuanced aspects of this procedure including the effect of lobbying on policy decisions, the interplay between consumers (such as incentives to free-ride), etc. It also makes some pretty critical assumptions, namely that the firm captures the full benefits of the costs imposed on the community which likely is not the case. Provided the deadweight losses arising from this issue are high enough, we can expect firms to gain significantly less than the burden they impose on consumers. The simple notion of the “enlightenment constant” nevertheless demonstrates how special interests have an advantage over dispersed interests and are able to leverage their informational advantage to rob the populace of its resources. |
A Regression Discontinuity Approach to the Effect of Immigration on Innovation in the USIn Chapter 4 of The Middle Income Trap, we learn that the US's status as an innovation powerhouse is at least partially a result of immigration. Sectors with a higher concentration of immigrants have experienced some of the largest growth since immigrant inventors generally have higher productivity than native-born inventors. I wanted to empirically test this theory, and I thought a good way to do this would be a regression discontinuity approach with the cutoff being the passage of the Immigration and Nationality Act of 1965, which abolished many US immigration restrictions and resulted in a wave of immigration to the US in the following years. If Chapter 4's argument is correct, we would expect a spike in patents (which act as a measure of innovation) following the passage of this new law. Using publicly available data from the US Patent Office on the total number of patents granted by year, I was able to run two regressions on the number of patents granted with respect to the years before 1965 and after 1965 with a lookback window of 30 years. This gave me a regression with 30 years of patents from the old policy and 30 years of patents with the new policy. Because the year the policy was passed is arbitrary, any difference just before 1965 and after 1965 gives us the treatment effect of increased immigrants on innovation. Doing so yields the following results: There is a clear discontinuity between the estimates before 1965 and after 1965, and looking at the counterfactual line, we can see that there is a clear spike in the number of patents granted. If we look at the size of the discontinuity (i.e., the treatment effect) based on the pre-treatment and post-treatment regression estimates for 1965, we get an increase of 9,070 patents thanks to the new immigration policy, which empirically supports Chapter 4's theory that immigration positively influenced innovation in the US. Of course, this assumes there were no covariates around 1965 that could have also led to the spike in patents. All code used can be found here. |
Political Lobbying and Harms to Creative Destruction in the Context of PG&E and California Wildfires Last week, I discussed how deep learning and AI could be utilized to detect and prevent future wildfires. With the wildfire devastations in Los Angeles, I am again thinking about how non-productive strategies, like political lobbying and connections, could have contributed to Californian wildfires in this week’s memo. The Schumpeterian Theory of creative destruction, as we learned about in the Aghion et al. text, emphasizes innovation’s role in driving economic and productivity growth by “destructing” outdated technologies. As seen in texts like the “Barriers to Creative Destruction” and “Connecting to Power” texts, many large firms rely on these non-productive strategies like garnering political connections, to maintain market dominance. PG&E, one of the largest utility companies in the U.S. that provides natural gas and electricity to millions of customers in California, has historically been at the center of California’s wildfire crisis. Experiencing lagging innovation and substantial improvements to their technologies, PG&E’s aging infrastructure has sparked catastrophic fires like the 2018 Camp Fire – which left 85 dead in California’s deadliest wildfire. Instead of investing in and proactively working on building innovative technologies, like underground power lines, AI-driven grid monitoring, or advanced weather forecasting technologies (which smaller firms and startups like Pano AI have been doing), PG&E has historically prioritized lobbying politicians for regulatory protections and liability limits. Having faced numerous lawsuits, like a $125 million settlement for the 2019 Kincade Fire, it makes sense that they need the support of politicians to sustain their company’s operations. ![]() (“Barrier to Creative Destruction” text, pg. 7) While lobbying provides immediate benefits (static benefits) like short-term cost savings and regulatory relief over many lawsuits, the long-term costs (dynamic losses) include higher wildfire risks, infrastructure failures, reduced public trust, and a multibillion-dollar bankruptcy filing in 2019. The “killer acquisition” analogy applies to PG&E here because their political lobbying efforts are actions to hinder competition from entering the market. This has led to slower market entry of smaller, innovative energy firms – a direct consequence of their non-productive strategies like we saw in Italy from the “Connecting to Power” text, where politically connected incumbents deterred market entrants and suppressed industry-wide innovation. Their focus on expanding market dominance reflects the idea about how politically connected firms display growth in revenue and size, but experience a stagnation in productivity. For the analytical element, I will interpret an equation from the Aghion et al. text (pg. 20) to illustrate PG&E’s resource allocation effects: ![]() Here, let Ze represent innovation contributed by new entrants (like Pano AI), Zi represent innovation contributed by incumbents, L represent the total resources available, and the rest of the variables representing parameters capturing efficiency, elasticity, and resource allocation dynamics. A higher Ze/(Ze + Zi) indicates that a greater share of productivity growth comes from new entrants. In PG&E’s case, smaller innovative firms like Pano AI represent Ze that focus on building wildfire prevention technologies. If PG&E allocates a large share of their total resources available (L) towards political lobbying, this would reduce Ze and suppress the potential for overall productivity growth. In other words, this could lead to higher wildfire threats and infrastructure failures in the future due to PG&E’s actions. |
Large foreign direct investment (FDI) projects, especially those valued at $500 million or more, are often praised for driving economic growth and bringing in cutting-edge technologies. By introducing both capital and managerial expertise, as well as connecting local businesses to global networks, FDI can help raise productivity and prepare domestic firms for international competition. However, recent research shows that when foreign investors gain majority ownership or exclusive partnerships, the initial benefits of FDI can shift from encouraging innovation to reducing competition. In such cases, foreign companies may rely on strategies that protect or expand their own market share at the expense of domestic firms, which can weaken the motivation for local innovation. This pattern reflects the issues highlighted in Barriers to Creative Destruction, where dominant market players—whether local or foreign—prioritize preserving their power instead of supporting vibrant, competitive markets. In some emerging economies, multinational companies leverage large patent portfolios, engage in lobbying for favorable regulations, or take advantage of easier access to infrastructure and financing to push aside local competitors. While foreign-owned firms can indeed boost initial economic indicators, they may also limit the opportunities for domestic businesses to develop new technologies and climb the “innovation ladder.” My research explores how foreign ownership influences innovation in local firms. I focus on whether a higher share of foreign equity leads to stronger research and development (R&D) efforts, or whether it simply encourages market consolidation. To do this, I will collect data on the percentage of foreign ownership in each firm, the level of market concentration across industries (using measures like the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index), and the availability of public support for R&D, such as subsidies or tax credits. The key question is whether stronger foreign participation enhances or undermines the domestic innovation process, and whether policy interventions—like targeted R&D incentives—can counter any negative effects of high foreign ownership. Ultimately, my goal is to provide insights for policymakers who want to ensure that large-scale FDI truly stimulates innovation. Such policies might include careful screening of major FDI deals so they do not create near-monopolies, along with training programs that strengthen the ability of domestic firms to learn from, and compete with, foreign investors. In addition, performance-based R&D incentives could help local firms stay committed to innovation, especially in industries characterized by a strong foreign presence. By balancing these interests, governments can make sure that FDI promotes sustainable economic growth and genuine technological progress. Simple Formula: Innova Intensity = R&D as a percentage of revenue |
The Formula Industry is Lobbying to Prevent Creative DestructionThe theory of Creative Destruction emphasizes the need for innovation to drive productivity (and ultimately economic) growth. Unfortunately, market leaders are incentivized to protect their high market shares by resisting creative destruction. One avenue for doing so involves utilizing political power. Rather than continuously innovating, they use politics to prevent the rise of competitors. The infant formula industry is an example of this. The natural competitor to infant formula is breastfeeding. The formula industry is not innovating nor exiting the market if it cannot compete against breastfeeding. To protect themselves against breastfeeding, the formula industry is lobbying against policies that would benefit breastfeeding – namely against paid maternal leave. To understand the incentive of the formula industry to lobby against paid maternity leave, I calculated the loss in market share it would experience if a 12-week paid maternity leave were implemented in the United States. I assume the following: According to Allied Market Research, the U.S. baby infant formula market size was valued at $3,962.7 million in 2022. Table 1: Reductions in Breastfeeding if Paid Leave Were Implemented I calculated Reduced Formula Use = (Formula Use with 0 Weeks – Formula Use with 12 Weeks) / Formula Use with 0 Weeks. I calculated the market size of Abbot, Nestle, and Gerber using their market share. Then the market size of each subgroup using a 2:1 ratio between <6-month-old babies and >6-month-old-babies. Using the reduced formula used for each subgroup, I calculated the new market sizes. By adding the sub-market sizes, I found the new market sizes. Table 2: Calculation of Reduced Market Size The implementation of a 12-week paid leave would have resulted in a loss of $509 million for Abbot, $735 million for Mead Johnson, and $339 million for Nestle in 2022. In addition, the formula industry is projected to reach about $7,000 million by 2032, which leads to even greater losses for these companies. |
Modeling the impact of foreign direct investment (FDI) on innovation in ChinaHow does foreign direct investment impact innovation in China? Previous literature suggests mixed results. FDI-driven competition can have contrasting impacts on innovation (Aghion et al., 2005). On one side, increased competition from foreign firms may push domestic companies to innovate more aggressively to maintain their competitive edge—an effect known as the escape-competition effect. On the other side, the presence of foreign competitors can shrink the market share of domestic firms, lowering their profitability and, consequently, their incentive to innovate. This is referred to as the business-stealing effect. A key milestone in China’s foreign investment policy framework is the passage of “Foreign Investment Law” (FIL) in March 2019. Since its accession to WTO in 2002, China has become the world’s top recipient of FDI, with over 2.1 trillion US dollars of accumulated FDI by the end of 2018. The FIL calls for a gradual elimination of caps on foreign ownership in key Chinese industries, marking an important shift toward a more unionized and liberalized policy stance on FDI injection. I propose that the enactment of FIL can be treated as an exogenous variable, given that it was not influenced by the behavior of domestic firms and that the changes were externally imposed. Hence, we can employ a Difference-in-Difference (DiD) approach to isolate the causal relationship between FDI and innovation in China by leveraging the 2019 FIL legislation as an instrumental variable. Two-stage regression model:The first stage regression estimates the relationship between the FIE legislation changes and FDI intensity where:
Using the predicted FDI_Industry from the first stage, the second stage examines the impact of FDI on firm innovation: Where:
Key Assumptions
|
Capital Misallocation by Venture Capital FundsIn Creation, the World Bank proposes that American start-ups face pressure from a “get in, get out” culture, and that value-add firms in the US attract investment to grow without government intervention that can lead to capital misallocation. This reasoning is also used to justify the high flow rate of small firms, as they either develop into middle-sized firms or exit the market; and ultimately, the authors recognize this trend as evidence of the selectivity of private markets in the US. Implicit in this rationale is that firm lifetime in the US is an indicator of value, as it must have attracted sufficient investment to survive. I believe that this implication is overly optimistic of early-stage investments in US private markets. Venture capital (VC) funding is instrumental to the development of start-ups to middle-sized firms, and yet VC is riddled with its own pressures that can contribute to investment into––and growth of––non-value-add companies, like the role of governments in middle-income countries. VC firms need to carefully identify investments within bubbles and face the competitive politics of leading series rounds. A misallocation of capital through VC in a non-value-add firm may only be realized in a later stage of a company––when its deficiencies grow larger than its persuasive power toward VC partners in winning investment. Suppose we define a “wasted deal” as a venture capital funding round for a company that eventually goes out of business by 2025––either from bankruptcy, defaulting, or liquidation. A majority of start-ups fail in the seed round, which is a healthy indicator of VC selectivity and inevitable capital misallocation to discover value-add firms. Instead, suppose we only consider wasted deal sizes of above $1M, when firms have escaped the earliest vetting round by VC funds. For each year and size of funding round, we can define the wasted deal ratio as the number of wasted deals divided by the number of total deals. I gathered data from Pitchbook on ~120,000 VC deals and funding sizes since 2009 and plotted the data: One caveat is to understand the lag time for a wasted deal to be realized; for example, if a start-up raises in a series B round in 2014 but liquidates in 2018, it is still considered a wasted deal in 2014. This is why the downward sloping lines for each funding size may not represent improved vetting by VC funds or less misallocated capital, but instead that some subpar start-ups have yet to go out of business by 2025. A better indicator of improved capital allocation by VC funds is YoY slope; the steeper the line, the less the rate at which wasted deals are made, which can mean either i) start-ups are supporting and investing in fewer subpar companies, or ii) the lag time for a group of start-ups in that year is longer than before. But even in the case of ii), this can represent a marginally improved vetting process by VC funds, as companies taking longer to fail may have offered value-add at some point. This is yet another caveat, since classifying a failed business as a “wasted” deal ignores any short-term value they added during their lifetime. The magnitude of waste ratios are larger for smaller funding rounds, which is expected––the 1M - 4.9M phase is still early for a start-up to encounter market difficulties. What’s more interesting is the closeness of waste ratios for deal sizes of 5M - 9.9M and 10M - 24.9M, and 10M - 24.9M and 25M+. These represent mature start-ups that likely take longer to go out of business by token of funding received from the deal. However, apart from 2012 and 2015, each pair of consecutive funding sizes have a maximum absolute distance of ~0.025, which suggests that VC funds faced difficulties in identifying value-add start-ups once they attracted enough attention to begin large fundraising rounds. These failed firms also represent the most significant amount of wasted capital. This trend hints at a larger tendency in private markets for investors to follow the crowd, which will eventually amplify inefficiencies––and wasted capital––in start-ups that originally went unnoticed. |
Malaysia, Once Again: Politics and the Middle Income TrapIn my previous memo, I talked about how Malaysia has made remarkable progress toward escaping the middle-income trap, but it still faces significant challenges in transitioning to a high-income economy. A major barrier is the role of political connections, which have led to inefficiencies and hinder innovation in businesses. Despite these challenges, Malaysia’s consistent efforts through targeted policies and investments show that progress is possible. Political Connections and Resource MisallocationPolitical patronage has long influenced Malaysia’s economy. Firms with strong political ties often benefit from easier access to financing, government contracts, and regulatory leniency. While these advantages can yield short-term gains, they frequently result in resource misallocation. Companies spend more time and resources maintaining political relationships than improving productivity or pursuing innovation. The New Economic Policy (NEP), implemented in 1971, is a clear example. It aimed to increase Bumiputera participation in the economy, but it unintentionally created “Ali Baba” arrangements. In these arrangements, Bumiputera individuals (Ali) acted as the official business owners, while non-Bumiputera partners (Baba) handled operations. This led to resources being allocated based on political or ethnic considerations rather than merit. A study of 834 Malaysian companies between 2000 and 2022 found that politically connected firms overinvest in less productive projects because of their access to preferential resources. This trend has reduced the efficiency of Malaysia’s resource allocation system. link Here, Malaysia’s performance in patents granted (Figure 9) remains far behind Taiwan and South Korea, emphasizing the inefficiencies from politically connected businesses. ![]() Impact on the Middle-Income TrapMalaysia’s reliance on political connections has contributed to this issue by limiting competition and discouraging innovation. When firms focus on political affiliations instead of market-driven strategies, they lose technological advancement and diversification, which are essential for economic growth. However, Malaysia has not been completely stymied by these challenges. As noted in last week’s memo, the World Bank recognizes Malaysia’s transformation into a key manufacturing exporter. Initiatives like the Economic Transformation Programme (ETP) have addressed some inefficiencies, emphasizing public transport improvements, high-value manufacturing, and innovation hubs. For example, industrial parks like Batu Kawan and infrastructure projects like the MRT system have enhanced Malaysia’s economic efficiency. link Export Sophistication and GDP (1980 vs. 2003): ![]() The broader implication is that government mismanagement has hindered Malaysia's economy, but other growth factors and strategic investments have gradually driven the country's progress. To overcome the middle-income trap, Malaysia must address the structural inefficiencies caused by political connections. Resources should be allocated based on merit rather than political ties. Recent high-growth sectors like semiconductors and AI require must prioritize innovation over short-term political gains. Malaysia’s globalist strategy under the 13th Malaysia Plan (13MP) shows its commitment to reform. Economy Minister Rafizi Ramli emphasized the importance of international partnerships and innovation in breaking free from the middle-income trap. Initiatives like Technology Park Malaysia (TPM) show how Malaysia can foster domestic innovation while attracting foreign investment. link Political connections have definitely hindered Malaysia’s economic growth by misallocating resources and slowing innovation. However, Malaysia has been adapting through strategic investments and policy reforms. I believe that by gradually shifting away from government ties, Malaysia can realistically achieve high-income status and (fully) escape the middle-income trap. *This is in response to Professor Akcigit's article "Connecting to Power: Political Connections, Innovations, and Firm Dynamics", where political ties is said to hinder growth and resources allocation. |
The process of creative destruction is fundamental to economic growth and innovation. By allowing outdated firms and practices to be replaced by new and more efficient competitors, creative destruction drives technological progress and market dynamism. However, this process can be influenced by various factors, including venture capital (VC) investment and government support. In class discussions and readings, we explored the role of political connections in hindering creative destruction. The question I posted for the readings was on whether VC firms are a help or hindrance to creative destruction. Thus, for my memo, I thought it would be interesting to dive deeper into this topic. |
Hypothesizing the Role of Market Dynamics and R&D in Patenting Strategies In today’s economy, the way companies approach patenting has a significant impact on competition and innovation. However, not all patenting is about driving progress. Some firms engage in non-productive patenting—using patents strategically to block competitors rather than protect real innovations—which can stifle industry growth and creativity. To explore what shapes these patenting strategies, I developed a regression model that examines how much emphasis a firm places on innovation-driven patenting (represented by α) in its approach. The proposed model is as follows: Where:
For each of the regression coefficients, here are the hypotheses:
This model hypothesizes that firms with lower market share and higher R&D intensity are more likely to adopt patenting strategies driven by genuine innovation, whereas firms operating in rapidly growing industries may gravitate toward defensive practices. In order to test this model, you could use data from firms' patenting activity, innovation output, market share, industry characteristics, and R&D investment. It could provide empirical evidence for the relationship between firm characteristics, industry dynamics, and the extent of non-productive patenting, which might be valuable in shaping policies aimed at addressing the potential negative consequences of non-productive patenting on competition and innovation. |
Argentina provides an interesting case to examine the interplay between innovation, political connections, and economic growth, paralleling studies like "Connecting to Power: Political Connections, Innovation, and Firm Dynamics." Using Argentina-specific data on patents granted, economic freedom, and corruption perception, I analyze how these variables correlate and draw insights from Schumpeterian growth theory and the concept of creative destruction. From 2008 to 2011, patent approvals in Argentina remained constant at around 1,300 a year. At the same time, Argentina declined a bit in terms of economic freedom. Then, in 2012, patent approvals sank to 932, coinciding with a big drop in economic freedom that caused Argentina to be classified as a “repressed” nation for the first time. The correlation between these two variables weakened a bit over the next 4 years, during which patent approvals increased gradually while economic freedom decreased gradually. Corruption levels also worsened during this period, with several high-profile scandals involving Argentina’s president and state-sponsored businessmen. However, in 2017, when a new, more market-friendly administration took office, some regulations, such as foreign exchange market controls, were relaxed, and Argentina jumped back up to pre-2012 levels in the economic freedom index. This year also saw corruption decrease, and patent approvals surged to 2,301. Finally, from 2017 until the present, Argentina’s economic freedom and corruption rating have dipped slightly while patent approvals have fallen dramatically to a level almost as low as in the 2008-2011 period. The interventionist Peronists returned to power in 2019, exacerbating adverse economic conditions. All in all, throughout all these years of data, patent approvals, economic freedom, and corruption perception showed a notable relationship. The fluctuation in innovation activity reflected the broader economic volatility and regulatory landscape faced by Argentine firms, as well as the growth of politically connected companies that received billions in government contracts. High levels of regulation and weak property rights contributed to slowdowns in innovation by stifling competitive markets with policies that favored preserving government-protected industries instead of creative destruction. The barriers to creative destruction in Argentina bear similarities to those observed in Italy. High corruption levels and regulatory capture create a challenging environment for new entrants, discouraging competition and limiting resource reallocation to more innovative firms. This dynamic aligns with Schumpeterian growth theory, which emphasizes the necessity of competition for fostering creative destruction and driving technological advancement. In Argentina, however, entrenched incumbents often benefit from their connections, further stifling opportunities for innovation. The decline in patent grants after 2020 suggests a reduction in investment in innovation, potentially due to economic instability and the prioritization of rent-seeking behaviors by politically connected firms. This pattern mirrors findings in Italy between 1993 and 2014, where political connections offered firms short-term survival benefits but discouraged long-term innovation. The correlation between declining economic freedom and stagnation in innovation highlights the detrimental impact of excessive regulation on entrepreneurial activity and technological diffusion. Argentina’s experience greatly resembles Italy’s and reinforces the importance of limiting political interference and fostering market competition to achieve sustainable growth with creative destruction. |
Cruise and Waymo -- application of the political economy of creative destructionIn October of 2023, a woman was hit and dragged by a Cruise AV in San Francisco, hospitalized with serious injuries. This event eventually led to the California DMV suspending Cruise's license to operate AVs, forcing Cruise to recall its entire fleet from San Francisco, and GM to stop funding the Cruise unit (Cruise was acquired by GM pre-crash for $1b). With Cruise and GM seeming to pull out entirely from the AV industry, Waymo, Google's AV unit, was essentially left as the last (developed, deployed, and fully autonomous) man standing. What's interesting in these details was that the CDMV's decision to revoke Cruise's operating license comes only in part from deeming the technology as unsafe -- the other part was believing "the company misrepresented the incident." (source here) While going into a data analysis of Cruise versus Waymo crashes might be helpful and lend a more nuanced view to the CDMV's decision, it might be summarized as such: Waymo has a higher crash rate than Cruise, but Waymo claims that higher rate is due to others hitting their stationary vehicles (~55% of the time), and from having more cars driving more miles than Cruise. Cruise has a higher injury rate from their crashes, at ~20%. In this sense, Cruise might have a more dangerous technology compared to Waymo, but still outperforms humans in comparable driving environments, here. I don't wish to claim that Waymo and Cruise were equals in technology or safety because I'm not certain that they were (and it seems that Waymo is generally considered better). Instead, I'm trying to look at the CDMV's decision from a political connections lens -- that Cruise and Waymo data seems somewhat comparable, and neither's technology was necessarily bad. At least one piece of evidence that might undermine this claim that both were in good standing (particularly because of the timing) is this incident that occurred in August 2023 where the DMV required Cruise to cut half of its operating fleet (roughly two months before this second decision to revoke the license entirely). In a report published by a law firm Cruise and GM had hired, it was "found that while the [Cruise / GM] executives had not intentionally misled state officials, they had failed to explain key details about the incident...The summary of the report was a long list of reasons to explain why regulators accused Cruise of misleading them." source here) One reason includes state officials claiming that Cruise did not share the entire video of the crash; another relates to the Cruise team not explaining the technology / decision-making of the car as it went through the incident. Therefore, it seems that the decision to revoke the operating license was somewhat personal -- one made off of principles of honesty instead of safety. A consequence that could have been potentially avoided had Cruise constructed better political relationships. Local officials (those in San Francisco) have been the most critical of AVs (especially Fire Departments) but they also have no control of AV activity -- that power lies completely in the California DMV and Public Utilities Commission. Since Jan 2021 to June 2023, Cruise spent ~$800k on lobbying in Sacramento (California capital). In that same period, Waymo spent ~$1.2m, with half of that coming in the months before an August 10th vote that gave the two companies 24/7 operating licenses. In 2022, Cruise gave $50k to support Gavin Newsom's reelection as governor, and it is believed that Cruise's state-level strategy was organized by one of the governor's closest associates. Cruise also has ties to the CPUC, as one of their former managing counsels now serves on the state utilities commission, having been appointed by Newsom. However, Waymo still outspent Cruise in total lobbying, and more recently in 2024 got Newsom to veto a bill they were against. It seems intellectually dishonest to make the claim that Cruise was shut down due solely to a lack of quality political relationships. But it doesn't seem incredibly intellectually dishonest to claim that the CDMV's decision to revoke Cruise's operating license had some human relationship / trust element to it. Either way, Waymo is now the only one standing (though there are new startups, notably Zoox and even Tesla), and it seems that some competitive environment that kept some innovating flame in the two companies has been extinguished. |
Incumbents and Cannibalization: Investigating when Incumbents InnovateIn "Barriers to Creative Destruction", Baslandze notes that incumbents often benefit less from innovation due to the risk of "cannibalizing the firms' own rents". Thus, they have an incentive to block creative destruction through the use of strategic patenting. Building upon the innovation technology model discussed in class, this phenomenon can be represented simply as follows for a given incumbent originally making monopoly profits: Given Standard Case (No action): If creative destruction occurs, the firm is pushed out of the market by competitors. Otherwise the firm makes standard profits with old technology Innovation Case (Firm chooses to innovate): Since new products are direct substitutes to existing ones, successful innovation with probability Strategic Patenting Case: By obtaining patents with cost denoted by Hence, opting for strategic patenting can be viewed as a form of insurance for the incumbent. Although innovating can potentially protect incumbents from externally occuring creative destruction, cannibalization acts as a ceiling against the profits the incumbent can earn. Thus, risk averse incumbents and incumbents operating in markets with high costs of research and development may see strategic patenting as an attractive option. Since cost of research is a function of Special Case: SoftwareSoftware is an area that I would like to examine more closely. Since software IP is traditionally governed by copyright law rather than patents (due to difficulty of meeting patent criteria), an industry specific model should either remove the option to strategically patent or significantly increase |
Political connections influence the market by giving the incumbent a cost advantage: lower marginal cost, by removing regulatory taxes. Due to technological improvements, new entrants must create a good with a significantly higher cost advantage to replace the incumbent’s good. When the improvement is smaller than the value of the regulatory tax, the incumbent’s good is not replaced. Perhaps we live in a world where there will be an immediate public outcry for tax evasion due to political connections. Then we can still approach this problem from another angle and reach a similar conclusion. Instead of having the value of the tax as the reduction in marginal cost for an incumbent, we could argue that there are frictions in supplying goods that are overcome by bribing distributors. For example, say a distributor must decide between supplying Firm A or Firm B’s goods, and A is politically connected, but B is not. Firm A uses its political connections to bribe the supermarket with a one-time lump sum transfer in order to supply good A instead of good B. Further, bribes can be cheaper with greater political connections. The model is different because now, both face the same marginal costs, but whether a firm can get profits is determined by which good the supplier decides to supply. In this world, both firms are supplying the exact same good at time 0, with the same marginal revenue and marginal cost, and monopoly profits for whichever firm gets its goods distributed by the supplier (reflecting the idea of a dominating incumbent). Both firms have political connections, but one has stronger political connections than the other. Stronger political connections allow a firm to have their goods distributed at a lower bribery cost, because the politicians influence the decision of the supplier through some benefits/other measure (could be a range of things). The decision that the supplier makes in choosing between either firm can be modelled by an equation: Benefit from supply = bribe * political connection Thus, for firms that differ only by political connection, the firm with greater political connections can profit. In each time period, the incumbent firm risks being overtaken with probability p. Therefore, the cumulative profit that a firm gets from supplying its goods can be graphed as below: Diminishing expected profits in each period reflects constant profits discounted by a higher probability of another firm being able to offer a higher bribe due to a technological improvement that allows them to offer a higher bribe, which eventually convinces the supplier to choose to distribute that other good instead. The maximum bribe a firm is willing to pay at time t is the area under the curve. This value is higher with greater profit margins created by technological increases. At time 0, when goods are identical, the firm with stronger political connections benefits by being able to offer a lower bribe than the firm with weaker connections and still having its goods distributed. Hence, they profit. The incentive to politically connect is no longer related to the ongoing tax but is a result of a desire for future profits decided at discrete time periods right before the distributor chooses whose goods to supply. |
Higher Education and Innovation: The Formal Qualifications of Global R&D Personnel Since 2000 Both “Connecting to Power” and “Barriers to Creative Destruction” explore the role of large firms in creative destruction. While some incumbents might adopt a pro-competitive model in support of creative destruction and innovation, other incumbents choose a more cost-efficient, anti-competitive model that drives entrants out of the economy. What is the role of higher education in innovation? On one hand, we think of higher education as the hub of innovation. Students who have been through academic training are equipped with various skills necessary for R&D research. On the other hand, aren’t universities also large, old organizations that establish themselves primarily through history, prestige, and even political connections? They seem to be potential candidates for the preservation force or dominant structure in innovation. This week, I began exploring datasets on the relationship between innovation and higher education. As my first step into the topic, I conducted basic data analyses, which yielded some initial graphs related to this topic. To be specific, I gathered data about R&D personnel by sector of performance and formal qualification from The OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). This dataset provides various statistics about around 60,000 individuals employed directly in the field of R&D from 2000 to 2022. I summarized the distribution of R&D Personnel by country in the graph below. I also provided a graph summarizing the distribution of R&D Personnel by Education level (excluding the education level denoting “Total,” which can mean any level of education and not informative). It is clear from the data that among all educational backgrounds, R&D personnel who obtained a doctoral degree or its equivalent form the largest group. To investigate this subgroup more closely, I plotted the percentage of doctoral-level personnel against time. I also created a regression line visualizing the trend. Here, we see a rising proportion of R&D personnel who obtain doctoral-level over time. The outliers in 2021 and 2022 are curious but might be explained by issues during data collection. In “Tapping into Talent: Coupling Education and Innovation Policies for Economic Growth,” Ufuk Akcigit et al. highlight the development of scarce talent and career choice as a crucial thread in understanding and possibly intervening in innovation and growth. Although this paper focuses directly on inventors instead of R&D personnel, my result resonates with one of the facts discovered in the sense that PhDs are more likely to engage in innovation compared to the average person in society. Based on its discoveries of the development of scarce talent, the paper proceeds with the discussion of the impact of R&D and Education policies on the development of innovators. I wonder if I could also start with an exploration of innovative talents (R&D personnel) and continue with more policy discussion. ![]() ![]() ![]() ![]() |
Scoring Entry Feasibility in Indonesia’s Biotechnology MarketI develop a potential model that assigns a creative destruction “score,” which can be used to determine whether the market conditions for new entrants are favorable. Here, new entrants are used as a proxy for creative destruction, as successful disruptors are a key part of that process. I apply information from The World Bank Group’s “Chapter 4: Creation” and Akcigit, Baslandze, and Lotti’s “Connecting to Power” to define model parameters. The The World Bank group claims that middle income countries have higher barriers to entry and are less likely to have effective creative destruction (hence the middle income trap). In these countries, incumbents are more likely to block entry and prevent innovation. So, in this case, we would expect something like InnovInt is the innovation intensity of an industry, which contributes positively to our score as more innovation should make it easier for a new entrant to gain market power. Based on data I could find, I set For competition, I will use Regulatory burden and political connections in an industry generally would have a negative effect on new entrants, hence the negative signs. Regulation may be quantified by the number of laws/policies for new entrants. For the PolConn score, we could find the ratio of total incumbents in an industry with political connections. In the future, I’d include a term that accounts for the interaction between RegBurden and PolCon. Akcigit's model shows that a firm with political connections allows it to mitigate regulatory red tape, and by combining these two terms, we can account for the combined effects. I was not able to find good data for these values, so I’ll leave these as placeholders. To expand on this model, I would first need to develop methods for RegBurden and PolConn values. Also, the score itself must be compared against other industries or countries to make sense of the scale. Still, this serves as one way to view the connections between innovation, growth, and competition with creation. |
After reviewing "Barriers to Creative Destruction: Large Firms and Non-Productive Strategies" and "Connecting to Power: Political Connections, Innovation, and Firm Dynamics," it's clear that both papers critique non-productive strategies like political alliance employed by large incumbent firms to protect themselves from creative destruction and that the process of creative destruction is hampered by the consolidation of capital and political power at the higher end of the firm size distribution. This lagging innovation as a result of political connectedness with large firms is demonstrated by the data collected in Italy pertaining to the political influence of large incumbent firms and correlated election effects on expected firm size. I wanted to explore this concept of political connectedness negatively affecting innovation across the global economy to see if this effect is generalizable internationally, beyond the data we've seen in Italy. I found data from the American Economics Association detailing the "Country Distribution of Firms with Political Connections" in a paper that similarly explores political connectedness of firms titled, "Politically Connected Firms." The data shows different countries' connected firms as percentage of market capitalization, which I combined with the most recent Real GDP Growth per Capita data to unveil any trends between productivity and political influence as a proportion of market capitalization across several countries. The trend line in the following graph suggests that countries with smaller capitalized representations of politically allied firms usually had higher Real GDP growth per capita based on GDP data ranging from 2022-2023. Therefore, the graph below suggests that the connection between political connectedness and lower innovation can roughly be generalized to global economies. This extension confirms that large incumbent firms representing significant shares of a country's market cap and exercising non-productive strategies like political alliance as opposed to R&D spend, decreases recent real GDP growth per capita, a proxy for recent advances in labor productivity. ![]() Sources: American Economic Review https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/000282806776157704 |
Memo: Barriers to Creative Destruction and Their Implications for Innovation To summarize the key themes of our lectures this week, the Schumpeterian concept of creative destruction emphasizes how innovation by new entrants disrupts existing markets, fostering economic growth. However, as outlined in Baslandze’s review, large firms often employ three common non-productive strategies, such as political connections, anti-competitive acquisitions, and non-productive patenting, to stifle this process (p. 2). These behaviors are particularly prevalent in heavily regulated environments like Italy (p. 4). By suppressing the reallocation of resources toward innovative entrants, such strategies hinder economic growth, contributing to declining business dynamism and stagnant productivity in advanced economies like the U.S. (p. 5). This reflects a troubling shift in incentives, where incumbents focus on protecting existing rents instead of fostering innovation, resulting in long-term economic inefficiencies (p. 7).
However, as we transition to the digital era, the landscape of creative destruction has evolved significantly, with technology giants like Meta and Google playing a dominant role. These companies embody a duality: on one hand, they drive innovation through groundbreaking advancements in AI and digital platforms; on the other, they engage in practices such as frequent acquisitions of small, highly innovative SaaS companies. While these acquisitions can integrate new ideas into dominant platforms, boosting short-term innovation, they also contribute to market consolidation, reducing opportunities for smaller competitors and potentially stifling broader market dynamism. This duality makes it more difficult for policymakers to navigate the tradeoff between monopoly power and innovation - can a corporation balance both of these dynamics? These acquisitions can simultaneously exhibit elements of creative destruction, integrating new ideas into dominant platforms, and market consolidation that limits broader competitive dynamics. Economic Model of Innovation and Market Concentration: I(A,C)=αA−βC Where: Market Concentration Impact: Market concentration (MC) is positively related to acquisitions (A): MC=γA Where: Net Innovation Effect: The net effect on innovation (NI) accounts for both integration and competition: Where: Hypotheses for Value Interactions The relationship between acquisitions, market concentration, competition, and innovation highlights the delicate balance needed to maintain a dynamic and competitive market. For companies like Google, whose innovation drives progress but also consolidates power, it is clear that thoughtful policy decisions are essential to encourage creativity while preserving fair competition. |
In “Connecting to Power”, the link between political connections, firm survival and innovation rate was established. A leadership paradox became clear – market leaders tended to be politically connected, leading to higher employment and revenue, but coming at the expense of innovation. One of these mechanisms that I (very reductively) understood was that they could use these political connections to maintain their market dominance through uncompetitive measures like raising the barriers to entry by restricting the ease of obtaining a license to operate etc. Without political connetions, the main way through which these incumbents would maintain their dominance would be through out-innovating their competition. Instead, they spend money that could have been used in R&D to instead lobby politicians to help them use government regulation to uphold their market dominance. This got me thinking, above and beyond having political connections per se, would it not also be imperative to look at the political situation of the country? The assumption underlying the analysis is that politicians who join the companies would necessarily be willing and able to help the companies enact anti competitive measures at the risk of being seen as corrupt. Hence, I thought it might be interesting to also look at other variables that might impact this mechanism linking political connections to the enactment of anti competitive measures. In essence, is there also a correlation between the political climate and innovation? Namely, I looked at the extent of political turmoil and the extent of corruption. For the former, my intuition was that the more political turmoil, the less the extent of correlation between political connections and innovation as even with political connections. If these connections can’t stay in power long enough, they might not be able to enact long-standing, impactful policies that effectively deter entrants. For the latter, I would think that the more corrupt a country is, the more likely it is for these political connections to enact anti competitive measures and hence dampen innovation. I chose to compare Singapore and Venezuela, countries that have notably different political situations. Here are the graphs I came up with using the Fragile State index and Perceived Corruption Index. And here’s what I have for Corruption Perceptions Index. Doing a really simple summary statistics, we can see that for the FSI, there seems to be an inverse relationship between the FSI and innovation. The more fragile a state becomes, the less innovation comes out of it. This makes intuitive sense, even if there are many politicians who are connected to the company, if the political situation is fragile, they might not be able to effectively enact the anticompetitive policies. The trend is less obvious for Singapore, perhaps because our political situation has not experienced much change in a while. For the corruption index, due to a lack of data, we’ll focus instead on comparing the general levels of innovation. Obviously, Singapore with it’s relatively much less corrupt government, enjoys a much higher rate of innovation than Venezuela, which consistently ranks in the bottom quartile of the corruption index. Of course, Sum Stats are often subject to noise and can be but spurious correlations, and so we must be cognizant not to conclude any causal relationship just yet. That said, there is definitely room to use these as variables in our regressions to confirm the robustness of our conclusions from the “Connecting to Power” paper. Apart from simply having politicians on board, what are the other factors (political instability, degree to which the politicians are willing to enact anti competitive measures) that we should factor into our regressions, to correctly isolate the causal relationship between political connection and innovation outcomes. Sources: |
Through Barriers to Creative Destruction: Large Firms and Non-Productive Strategies, we are presented with the lack of progress that is driven by incumbent’s fear of being replaced. There are various strategies put into place from using patents as an overbearing defense mechanism, using political connections to abuse power, and even acquiring potential rival firms: nipping any competition in the bud. |
Memo: Contract Institutions, Creative Destruction, and Robot Adoption in ChinaThis memo integrates Schumpeterian growth theory with contract institutions to propose a framework for understanding how contract incompleteness affects robot adoption and creative destruction in China's manufacturing sector. By linking institutional quality, technological innovation, and productivity growth, the framework provides insights into the mechanisms underlying technological upgrading. Building on the Schumpeterian framework of creative destruction and incorporating contract institutions, I propose: Where:
This equation combines: The classic Schumpeterian growth equation ( This model helps explain key empirical patterns observed in China's manufacturing sector. First, it accounts for the inverted-U relationship between competition and innovation, as industries with moderate competition foster optimal conditions for creative destruction. Second, it explains why robot adoption is more prevalent in industries with complex production processes and weak contract enforcement; in such settings, firms turn to automation as a substitute for institutional reliability. Finally, the framework emphasizes the critical role of creative destruction in driving technological progress, illustrating how firms with robust institutional support more effectively implement disruptive technologies. Chinese manufacturing firms have been at the forefront of global robot adoption, accounting for 52.48% of installations in 2022 according to the IFR. However, this trend reveals significant regional disparities driven by differences in contract enforcement quality. In coastal provinces such as Jiangsu and Zhejiang, stronger institutional frameworks enable firms to rely on external contractors, reducing the necessity for automation. In contrast, interior provinces like Sichuan and Gansu, where contract enforcement is weaker, experience higher rates of robot adoption. This variation reflects a strategic response by firms in weaker institutional environments, where automation serves as a substitute for unreliable contractual arrangements, particularly in industries with high production complexity. The impact of contract enforcement on robot adoption is further evident in sectoral differences. In high-complexity industries, such as electronics and automotive manufacturing, weak institutions impose higher transaction costs, resulting in a stronger incentive to adopt robots. Empirical data shows that weak enforcement quality significantly reduces productivity growth in these sectors, as these industries rely less on external contracting and are less sensitive to institutional quality. Over time, Chinese firms in regions with weaker contract enforcement have consistently adopted robots at higher rates, particularly in industries with greater production complexity. This trend underscores how institutional weaknesses shape firm behavior, driving technological adoption as a way to internalize production processes and mitigate risks associated with external contracting. For example, during the early 2000s, industries such as automotive manufacturing saw a sharp rise in robot adoption in regions with weak contract enforcement, where firms faced mounting challenges from unreliable external partners. The case of Chinese manufacturing underscores the broader implications of institutional quality on technological adoption. Weak contract enforcement drives firms to adopt robots as both a tool for improving efficiency and a strategic response to institutional shortcomings. Strengthening contract enforcement could reduce firms’ reliance on automation as a substitute for external contracting, fostering more balanced growth across regions. |
Innovation as the Key to Escaping the Middle-Income Trap The Innovation Challenge Case in Point: The Republic of Korea The Innovation-Growth Link Y(t)=A(t) * K(t)^α * L(t)^(1−α) Here: We assume productivity grows exponentially with innovation: A(t)=A_0 * e^(γt) Where: This equation tells us that for a country to keep growing, it needs to continuously improve productivity through innovation (γ). For middle-income countries, boosting innovation through better policies, more R&D, and stronger global connections is key to reaching high-income status. The chapter makes it clear that countries aiming to escape the middle-income trap need to prioritize innovation. It’s not just about making small improvements but about creating an environment where big, transformative ideas can thrive. Korea’s experience shows how a deliberate focus on innovation can change a country’s future, offering valuable lessons for others stuck in the same spot. |
In “Connecting to Power: Political Connections, Innovation, and Firm Dynamics” Ufuk Akcigit, Salome Baslandze, and Francesca Lotti, we learn that firm level political connections are widespread, especially among large firms, and that industries with large share of politically connected firms are likely to innovate. I propose that the innovation outcome of a firm i in country c at time t could be modeled as: Where:
Hypotheses: Prevalence of family ties and a social network with politicians, and a healthy corruption score are positively connected with growth in size, and associated negatively with future growth in productivity measures. I am also curious if other variables could be added to analyze firm growth:
And if we can analyze the effect of political connectivity on:
|
In Barriers to Creative Destruction: Large Firms and Non-Productive Strategies, the argument is made that overtime, the patents firms apply for become increasingly similar as their speed of innovation slows down: “with the help of textual analysis and machine learning tools, patent applications that are too similar to their predecessors could be singled out and their necessity and applicability could be scrutinized” (15). It would be interesting to use NLP to analyze the similarity between different patents over time. This is empirically very feasible because all patent applications are public. Below is an illustration of the basic process that would occur in order to analyze similarity between different texts. First, the texts need to be tokenized and vectorized. Then, generate world and sentence embeddings in order to capture semantic meaning. Lastly, run a similarity model on the texts using Jaccard, Levenshtein, or cosine distance. I do not have sufficient understanding of NLP to know which type of distance is most suitable in this instance, but all of them should give a score between 0 and 1, loosely understood as percent similarity. The graph is meant to illustrate that the firm’s age and similarity scores (of the last n patents, however many one should choose to analyze) should be positively correlated. The relationship could be exponential, linear, or quadratic, which we can interpret as the rate at which innovation slows down. In theory, the older firms will produce more similar patents than younger firms. In discussing this with a friend who wants to work in patent law, she informed me that oftentimes a company’s new patent will refer to previous patents rather than restating what was previously written. To what extent this would affect the similarity score is unclear. Along these lines, another way of testing for originality would be counting the number of times the new patent refers to previous patents, with less references being more originality. The other thing to consider is how to select which patent to compare. Is it the last two patents? Or could we compare patents from the same company overtime? For example, we could take four patents from Meta—2010 vs. 2015 and 2019 vs. 2024. The gap of five years is arbitrary—I am not sure what is the optimal number of years to compare the difference. The idea is that the first pair should have a lower similarity score than the second pair, or the second pair references more previous patents than the first two pairs. Doing this across a set of 1000 firms over 40+ years old should generate a pretty solid picture of how innovation in these companies are slowing across time. |
Political Connections, Non-Productive Strategies, and Creative Destruction: Implications for Growth and Policy Role of Political Connections: Politically connected firms grow in size and revenue but exhibit lower labor productivity and innovation intensity (Akcigit et al.). Beyond political connections, large firms utilize non-productive patenting and acquisitions to deter competitors. Both papers emphasize the dynamic costs of these strategies, showing how they reduce the pace of creative destruction and aggregate productivity growth. Key Observation: Firms with higher market ranks (e.g., leaders) exhibit lower innovation intensity but greater reliance on political connections. This inverse relationship underscores the shift from productive to non-productive strategies as firms grow dominant. Policy Implications Transparency in Political Connections: |
The Implications of Innovative Efficiency on Patent Reform and Market StructureIn "Barriers to Creative Destruction: Large Firms and Non-Productive Strategies", Baslandze finds that large incumbent firms engage extensively in non-productive patenting to raise entry costs for competitors, thus hindering creative destruction. This phenomenon offers an alternative explanation for why TFP growth has stalled since the 1980s despite a massive surge in patenting, contrasting with Bloom et al's thesis that "low-hanging fruit" have been picked and ideas are becoming harder to find. While Baslandze's analysis of non-productive patenting practices is compelling, it doesn't necessarily preclude decreasing research productivity. Even if Bloom's study didn't fully account for non-productive strategies, Matt Clancy's preliminary analysis suggests that science itself is getting harder, using metrics relatively insulated from corporate activity like Nobel prizes and top-cited papers. Given the relationship between scientific advancement and innovation, this supports the notion that at least some productivity stagnation stems from declining research efficiency. During class, Professor Akcigit suggested considering patent reform in light of AI tools potentially increasing innovation efficiency, which could reduce justification for prolonged monopoly rents. This presents an interesting counterpoint to the declining innovation efficiency documented in the above research. To explore this, I used the Schumpeterian growth model we learned in class to investigate how revenues and costs change given either increasing or decreasing innovation efficiency parameters (lambda). Here is my simulation graph: The results are interesting—changes in innovation efficiency lead to markedly different profit trajectories, supporting Professor Akcigit's argument that extended monopoly profits become harder to justify as innovation becomes more efficient. However, under decreasing efficiency, profits remain relatively stagnant. Under this world, the arguable merits of the current patent system might be maintained. For instance, even with pharmaceuticals, where patenting practices face legitimate criticism, Ji and Rogers found that Medicare's regulated price cuts led to a 29% decline in new product introductions, suggesting monopoly rents play a role in enabling innovation. The second graph is particularly interesting—costs rise substantially even as revenues increase. This is particularly noteworthy because some economic models suggest that higher entry costs reduce the free-entry equilibrium number of firms, as each firm must capture greater market share to recover costs. Assuming that this model is applicable, this suggests that in a world of increasing innovative efficiency (or even just constant innovative efficiency), patent reform alone might not advance creative destruction, as market structures may naturally evolve toward oligopolies or monopolies. This implies that we may need more innovative policies to enable new entrants to continue creative destruction cycle (while being careful to avoid growth-inhibiting preferential policies). |
The pharmaceutical industry is placed in the crossroad between innovation and regulation. Heavily investing in R&D can yield groundbreaking therapies that improve public health outcomes, yet companies often also choose to invest heavily in lobbying to shape regulatory processes and gain market advantages. The work by Baslandze (2023) and Akcigit (2023) highlights this dilemma of “political-tiedness,” where firms shift resources from genuine R&D toward lobbying to secure favorable policy decisions. The scatterplot below is based on data from pharmaceutical firms that have spent more than $1,000,000 lobbying3 in the U.S. last year, and it illustrates a moderate correlation (R² = 0.47) between total lobbying expenditures in 2024 and FDA drug approvals between 2021 and 2024. While higher lobbying spending appears linked to more approvals, this pattern raises questions about whether such approvals represent transformative innovations or primarily reflect political leverage. Creative destruction suggests that entrenched players might use political connections to maintain dominance, thereby discouraging smaller firms from pursuing new treatments. Indeed, these findings echo Akcigit’s “leadership paradox,” where established incumbents can outmaneuver genuinely innovative challengers. A related concern is regulatory capture wherein regulatory agencies serve the interests of powerful industry actors. If lobbying funds simply accelerate approval for “me-too” drugs rather than groundbreaking therapies, then the public risks missing out on real medical advances. A more detailed examination of each approved drug’s therapeutic impact—perhaps by comparing clinical trial outcomes or novelty in patent filings—could help clarify whether lobbying expenditures drive genuine breakthroughs. These results pose important questions about how to balance lobbying activities with the pursuit of valuable innovations. Policymakers might consider reforms that ensure the regulatory process is tied more closely to verified clinical gains or introduce stricter transparency requirements around lobbying efforts. This could help curb any chance of political connections overshadowing the pharmaceutical industry’s central purpose: delivering truly novel and effective treatments to the patients who need them most.
|
Regulatory Burdens and Anti-Competitive Strategies: Impact on Innovation and Market Dynamics The regulation of firm sizes has long been a double-edged sword: while intended to promote fair practices and oversight, these policies often result in a number of unintended consequences that distort competition and discourage innovation. For example, France's 50-employee regulatory threshold imposes significant costs on firms that exceed it, leading many firms to stagnate just below the threshold to avoid additional regulatory burdens. For this week's memo, I extracted insights from an American Economic Association paper titled "The Impact of Regulation on Innovation", which highlights these dynamics and provides a critical lens through which to evaluate size-dependent policies. Impact on Innovation The figure above ("Total Innovation by Firms of Different Employment Sizes") displays the sharp decline in innovation activity just before the regulatory threshold-what one might call an "innovation valley." This sharp decline occurs because firms below the threshold seek to avoid crossing the threshold beyond which costs will skyrocket-for example, where additional labor regulations must be adhered to. Similarly, Panel A (Innovation) makes a more general comparison between the regulated and the unregulated environments: whereas in the unregulated contexts, innovation rises smoothly with firm size; in regulated ones, the threshold disrupts this natural process. The message is blunt: regulations with the purpose of 'fairness' may have an unplanned consequence for discouraging innovation, especially of smaller firms around critical size thresholds. Distorted Firm Size Distribution Another spillover of such regulations is how they affect the firm size distribution, which Panel B (Size Distribution) shows rather clearly. The chart dramatically illustrates how regulatory thresholds distort the natural size distribution of firms. Many firms deliberately remain below the threshold of 50 employees, which creates a visible "bulge" in the data, while the share of larger firms declines. But this practice undermines competition because large firms are protected from the pressures of smaller ones that might otherwise grow and challenge them. The result is a less dynamic economy, with less creative destruction- a key driver of growth. Policy Implications These findings have crucial implications. Rigid, size-dependent policies create sharp disincentives for growth and innovation in their efforts to address very legitimate concerns. Policymakers need to consider more graduated approaches, such as phasing regulatory requirements in as firms grow, rather than simply placing binary thresholds. A flexible framework could allow firms to grow and innovate without the fear of a sudden jump in costs. This approach would preserve the original goals of regulation while removing barriers that discourage growth. Conclusion The visual evidence here speaks volumes about how well-intended regulations can backfire, suppress innovation, and alter the competitive landscape. Revisiting such policies with a focus on flexibility and scalability is essential in fostering a vibrant economy. Without reform, size-dependent regulations risk holding back the very dynamism they aim to protect, leaving firms stuck in a pattern of stagnation. Meeting these challenges is critical for sustaining long-term growth and productivity. |
ARE RUSSIAN MICRO FIRMS STRUGGLING TO SCALE OR FINDING NEW PATHS TO GROWTH? In the readings and during class, Professor Akcigit highlighted that productivity growth, often proxied by the number of patents per capita, can be driven by both new entrants (e.g., the U.S.) and established incumbents (e.g., Germany). The World Development Report 2024 further showed that younger firms, which are typically small, account for the majority of net job creation. Building on this framework, I wanted to conduct a simple analysis in the Russian market, focusing specifically on micro and small firms to see if there are similar trends.
Unfortunately, there is no publicly available information on the number of the employees and the age of the firms, so I decided to look at the general trend of how the number of micro and small firms has been changing over years. I was able to find data on the number of “newly born” organizations, which are very vaguely defined in the literature and in the datasets themselves but assumed to refer to the number of newly registered firms in a given year. This term typically applies to micro firms, as it is challenging for a micro firm to grow into a small firm within a year. Interesting, however, 4 newly born small firms were recorded in 2023. In Figure 1, the percentage of newly born micro firms relative to the total number of micro firms has remained stable over the past eight years, fluctuating between 18% and 20% (excluding COVID years). This suggests that approximately 20% of micro firms are entering the market each year. However, Figure 2 reveals that the growth rate of micro firms is highly volatile, remaining below 6%, even turning negative in 2019-2020. Two possible scenarios could explain the trend before 2022: 1) a significant percentage of micro firms fail to survive or 2) some micro firms grow and transition into small firms. However, the decline in the number of micro firms correlates with a simultaneous decline in the number of small firms, with the percentage of small firms decreasing even more sharply. This indicates that the likelihood of micro firms transitioning into small firms is low. It means that first, it is difficult for micro firms to grow into larger firms with more than 15 employees. Second, the high attrition rate of micro firms suggests that most are probably exiting the market rather than scaling up. Unfortunately, due to the lack of data on the age of the firms, it’s challenging to determine whether these exits are due to inability of young, innovative startups tp survive or the long-anticipated decline of older micro firms. After 2022, the number of small firms has gradually increased. This growth over the past three years could be attributed to one of two factors. The first possibility is that medium-sized firms (those with fewer than 250 employees and profit of less than 2 billion rubles, ~ 20 million USD) may have downsized into the small firms. However, this is unlikely, as Figure 2 indicates that the number of medium-sized firms has been growing during this period. The second and more plausible explanation is that some micro firms actually managed to grow and transition into small firms, which could signal the potential for small, innovative firms to compete with well-established ones. However, these are just potential explanations, and further analysis is needed to draw more definitive conclusions. ![]() Figure 1 ![]() Figure 2 Data Source: Federal Tax Service of Russia. (2025). Statistics on small and medium-sized businesses. Retrieved January 10, 2025, from https://ofd.nalog.ru/statistics.html?statDate=10.01.2025&level=2&fo=&ssrf=&t=1737096973584&t=1737096973585 |
In Chapter 4 of the World Development Report 2024: The Middle-Income Trap, the authors emphasize how middle-income countries often fail to transition to high-income status when their economic growth model becomes trapped in sectors with limited scope for innovation. Simultaneously, Schumpeterian growth theory (Aghion, Akcigit, & Howitt, 2014) underscores the essential role of creative destruction—the entry of innovative firms displacing unproductive incumbents—in sustaining long-run growth. Integrating these perspectives, I argue that artificial intelligence can serve as a potent lever to overcome MIC stagnation, provided institutions avert policies that dampen the dynamism of new entrants. Despite AI’s promise, incumbent firms often use non-productive strategies (Barriers to Creative Destruction, Baslandze 2023) to defend existing market power—especially in MICs where policies may favor large, politically connected actors. For example, firms might lobby for size-dependent subsidies or preferential treatment, which can distort incentives for widespread adoption of AI-based innovation. This inertia stifles creative destruction, preventing smaller AI-driven startups from scaling up and challenging incumbents. However, if AI is democratized—through accessible machine-learning tools, supportive regulatory frameworks, and open innovation platforms—smaller firms in MICs can more effectively harness technology to boost productivity and disrupt entrenched incumbents. By lowering the barriers to data processing and R&D, AI can raise the likelihood of leapfrogging in sectors from agriculture (e.g., automated crop monitoring) to finance (e.g., digital lending services). These transformations become particularly powerful when accompanied by pro-competition reforms that reduce bureaucratic red tape, increase transparency in procurement, and limit preferential policies for incumbent firms. Analytical Element: Modeling AI-Enhanced Creative Destruction
As Ultimately, aligning AI investments with competitive, pro-innovation policies can help middle-income countries break free from the trap and cultivate sustained Schumpeterian growth. |
Post your memo in response any (or all) of the week's readings and an empirical case regarding artificial intelligence, innovation, and/or growth:
Post by Thursday @ midnight. By 1pm Friday, each student will up-vote (“thumbs up”) what they think are the five most interesting memos for that session. The memo should be 300–500 words (text) + 1 custom analytical element (e.g., equation, graphical figure, image, etc.) that supports or complements your argument. These memos should: 1) test out ideas and analyses you expect to become part of your final projects; and 2) involve a custom (non-hallucinated) theoretical and/or empirical demonstration that will result in the relevant analytical element. Because these memos relate to an empirical case students hope to further develop into a substantial final project and because they involve original analytical work, they will be very difficult to produce with generative AI and we strongly discourage you from attempting it. Some of the top-voted memos will form the backbone of discussion in our full class discussion and break-out room sessions.
The text was updated successfully, but these errors were encountered: